Of the five north-south issues mentioned
before, the issue of
returning fugitive slaves was not controversial. Pierce Butler of South Carolina
proposed that
a fugitive slave be returned on the same terms as a criminal. James Wilson and Roger Sherman made rather
tepid protests, and the issue was dropped. The next day, the issue was again
proposed and a requirement to
return a fugitive slave, euphemistically referred to as a “person bound to
service or labor by the laws of a state,” was adopted without opposition.
The other
four issues were more controversial. The
issue of slave representation was the first to be addressed. I learned in school that the Northern states
wanted to include slaves in taxation but not representation and the Southern
states wanted to include slaves in represenation but not taxation. This is an oversimplification. When the Articles of Confederation were
originally drawn up, the central government had no power to collect taxes, but
would collect them in quotas from the states.
Originally, each state’s quota was to be based on the value of land in
the state. When land values proved too
vague to be useable, each state’s quota was made proportional to its
population. This raised the question of
whether it would be proportional to a states’ total population or only its free
population. Naturally, Southern states
wanted to include only free population and Northern states wanted to include
total population. As a compromise, it
was agreed to include free population and three-fifths of all slaves,
euphemistically using the phrase:
The whole number of white and other free Citizens and
inhabitants of every age, sex and condition including those bound to servitude
for a term of years and three-fifths of all other persons not comprehended in
the foregoing description, except Indians not paying taxes.
During the
Constitutional Convention, controversy arose over how representation would be
apportioned in the lower house. Some
delegates proposed free population; some proposed tax revenue and some,
especially from South Carolina, where slaves made up an absolute majority of
the population, proposed wealth. As a
compromise, Charles Pinckney and James Wilson
proposed the same formula used
for tax revenue under the Articles. This time it was the Deep South that wanted
all slaves to be counted and the North that wanted them entirely excluded, and
each side accused the other of hypocrisy for reversing its position from what
it had been when the issue was taxation.
Gouverneur Morris then
proposed that they reduce controversy by saying
that direct taxation would be proportional to representation,
and James Wilson
suggested that they could reduce resistance further by saying
that representation would be proportional to taxation . This would make it appear that states were
being taxed by the 3/5 formula and represented according to the taxes they
paid. Seen that way, the three-fifths
rule appears almost reasonable except for one thing. The new government was not intended to be financed
either by tax quotas raised from states or from “direct” taxes, i.e., a fixed tax per head on
all free individuals and 3/5 of all slaves.
It would be financed primarily by import taxes and secondarily by a
variety of sales taxes. “Direct” taxes would make up only a tiny fraction of its total revenue, and often not even that. The linking of taxation and representation
was pure window dressing that both Morris and Wilson later criticized.
Up August
6, 1787, the Constitution was merely a series of resolutions which gave the
central government all powers for which the individual states are not
competent. On August 6, 1787 a committee
got together and prepared an actual
first draft of the Constitution, which
identified the specific powers of the general government and forbade certain
powers to the states. It also contained
three important concessions to the South:
(1)
Although Congress could regulate foreign trade, it
could not stop the “migration or importation of such persons as the states see
fit to admit,” i.e., slaves, or tax their import;
(2)
Exports could not be taxed;
(3)
No navigation act could be passed without a two-thirds
majority.
A navigation act is a law controlling shipping. What Northern states hoped for and Southern
states feared was that the federal government would require the South to export
its produce on American, i.e. Northern, ships.
England, previously the colonies’ main trading partner, had closed all
of the British Empire to American shipping, which had been a severe blow to the
trade-dependent New England states. New
Englanders wanted to give Congress the authority to regulate foreign trade in
order to retaliate and force open British ports, and to require Southerners to
send their exports on American ships as a substitute field of trade. Southerners feared that Northern merchants
would strangle them with high prices and monopolies. Outnumbered in both houses, they wanted to
require a two-thirds vote in order to have a veto on such laws. Since only South Carolina and Georgia really
wanted to keep importing slaves, requiring a two-thirds or even three-quarters
vote would not protect slave importation; only an absolute ban would suffice. The South also feared an export tax, not only
because it produced most of the U.S. exports, but because an export tax could
easily be made discriminatory. Virginia
had another reason to oppose a federal export tax – a tax on tobacco exports
was one of its major sources of revenue, and most people assumed that an export
tax would be exercised either by the federal government or the states.
Debate on
these issues became
hotter than on any issue other than representation. The New
England states threatened to secede unless Congress was given complete power to
regulate foreign trade by a simple majority.
The New England states were strong, their delegates boasted, and had
their own ships to defend themselves.
They could stand on their own.
The Southern states, without ships, would were vulnerable to attack and
should therefore support a navigation act that would encourage New England
shipbuilding for national defense. South Carolina and Georgia, on the other
hand, argued that they could not do without slaves and threatened to secede if
their slave imports were cut off. In the end, these issues were sent to a
committee that worked out a sectional compromise. Slave importation would be protected up to
1808, and slaves could be taxed at a limited rate. Neither the federal government nor the states
could tax exports. Navigation acts and
regulations of foreign trade would require only a simple majority. In effect, New England and the Deep South
shook hands on these issues behind Virginia’s back. The votes on these issues are revealing. On the importation of slaves, all New England
states joined with the Deep South to approve it, with the Upper South and the
Quaker states opposing. On the
regulation of foreign trade, every Northern state supported regulation by a
simple majority. Of the Southern states,
only South Carolina broke ranks. A
sectional compromise had been reached, and the
Virginians fumed in vain.
Those four issues, slave
representation, slave importation, export taxes and navigation acts, were the
four great sectional issues that divided the Convention. On most other issues, sectional differences
were most significant for their absence, but there were a few other issues that
showed sectional pattern.
One difference, noted before, is
that the southern states were the most nationalistic. Virginia and the states southward were the
ones that consistently favored the Virginia Plan over the New Jersey Plan and
opposed equality in the Senate.
Another was that the delegates
representing the commercial elite, i.e., almost all New Englanders and
Gouverneur Morris, speaking for the merchants of New York and Philadelphia,
opposed admitting Western states on an equal basis or setting a firm
rule for
reapportioning representation as population shifted. Virginians were the foremost advocates of the
West, with the South Carolina skeptical about the West, but not as hostile as
New England. Why?
One of the most basic reasons was
the one discussed in the last paper, that population in the South was growing
faster than in the North and Southerners therefore believed they would benefit
from future reapportionments and New England expected to lose. But that does not explain their attitudes
toward the West. Quite simply, members
of the commercial elite feared the West.
They saw themselves already a minority, commercial, seafaring and
outward looking, outnumbered by a majority that was agricultural, land-based
and inward looking. The more the country
expanded, the more agricultural, land-based and inward looking it would be and
the more the commercial interest would be outnumbered. Virginians had the opposite perspective,
agricultural, land-based and distrustful of merchants. Furthermore, Virginia included the present
state of Kentucky and had potentially immense land claims west of the
Appalachians. Although Virginia was
already planning to give up these enormous land claims, an extraordinary act of
statesmanship, even the potential claims led the Virginias to be particularly inward-looking
and see the West as their natural agricultural allies against commercial New
England. Strictly speaking, this did not
make a great deal of sense. Throughout
all the larger states there was strong conflict between western farmers and
eastern elites, and this conflict was just as strong in the South, where the
eastern elites consisted of planters as in the North, where the eastern elites
were merchants. This may, perhaps,
explain why South Carolina was not as strong a champion of the West as
Virginia; conflict between eastern planters and western farmers in South
Carolina was particularly strong.
Besides, South Carolina’s rice plantations were obviously restricted to
coastal swamps; Virginia’s tobacco plantations had better chances to expand.*
One final difference was that New Englanders
were most inclined to favor very short terms for office holders, especially
one-year terms for the House of Representatives. Very short terms were an old New England
tradition, going back to colonial times.
Keeping in mind that Massachusetts and Connecticut were the only New
England states present at the time, consider the
delegates who spoke up for a
one-year term in the House – Elbridge Gerry of Massachusetts, Caleb Strong of
Massachusetts, Oliver Ellsworth and Roger Sherman of Connecticut – and James
Wilson of Pennsylvania. A proposal for a
three-year term in the House was opposed by only three states, Massachusetts,
Connecticut – and South Carolina.
Massachusetts and Connecticut were holding out for a one-year term. South Carolina, whose officials all served
two-year terms, wanted a two year term, which would be more convenient for
their political cycle.**
On other issues, sectional
differences were most noticeable for their absence.